Multi-Currency Markets
Interest Rate Modeling
Tutorial Contents
- Fixed Income Notation
- Fixed Income Probability Measures
- Multi-Currency Markets
- The HJM Framework
- Basic Fixed Income Instruments
- Caps, Floors and Swaptions
- CMS Swaps, Caps and Floors
- Bermudan Swaptions
- Structured Notes and Exotic Swaps
- Callable Libor Exotics and TARNs
- Volatility Derivatives
- Yield Curves and Curve Construction
- Managing Yield Curve Risk
- Vanilla Models With Local Volatility
- Vanilla Models With Stochastic Volatility
- Introduction to Term Structure Models
- One-Factor Short Rate Models I
- One-Factor Short Rate Models II
- Multi-Factor Short Rate Models
- The Libor Market Model I
- The Libor Market Model II
- Risk Management and Sensitivity Computations
- P&L Attribution
- Payoff Smoothing
- Vegas in the Libor Market Model
Some derivatives depend on multiple currencies. If this is the case, the challenge of modeling such derivatives becomes
more difficult. In this section, we introduce a framework for modeling such multi-currency derivatives.
Notation
Consider a setup where we have two economies, a domestic economy and a foreign economy, each with their own
currency. In the following, we will denote the domestic currency by £ (GBP) and the foreign currency by $ (USD). Note
that these choices of currencies are arbitrary and are just used for
concreteness.
Let Pd(t,T) and Pf(t,T) denote the time t prices of T-bonds in the domestic and foreign economies,
respectively. Translating the value of the foreign T-bond to the domestic currency can be achieved at time t
through the spot FX rate X(t) measured in units of domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. In other
words, the value P^d(t,T) to a domestic investor of one foreign T-bond is
P^d(t,T)=X(t)Pf(t,T). FX Forwards
For no initial cash outlay, it is possible to generate a guaranteed cashflow at time T of one unit of foreign c
currency and −XT(t) units of domestic currency, where XT(t) represents the time t value of the
forward FX rate with maturity T. The strategy is as follows:
- Buy one foreign T-bond for P^d(t,T) in domestic currency.
- Finance this purchase by short-selling Pd(t,T)P^d(t,T)
units of the domestic T-bond. Clearly, this strategy is free to enter, and will generate a time T cashflow of
$1−£Pd(t,T)P^d(t,T). To preclude arbitrage, we find that this expression must be zero at time
t. Hence, we have locked in an exchange rate of
XT(t):=Pd(t,T)P^d(t,T)=X(t)Pd(t,T)Pf(t,T) at time t for an FX trade at maturity T.
Risk Neutral Measures
Let βd(t) and βf(t) denote the continuously compounded money markets in the domestic and foreign
economies, respectively. βd(t) and βf(t) induce two separate risk-neutral measures, which we denote by
Qd and Qf, respectively. Clearly, these two measures are related. If g(T) is a random
payoff at time T made in the foreign currency, in a complete market this payoff is worth
Vf(t)=βf(t)Etf[βf(T)g(T)], to the foreign investor, where Etf[⋅] represents the conditional expectation operator under
Qf. From the point of view of a domestic investor, the payoff g(T) must translate to a domestic currency
at a rate of X(T) at time T, making the effective domestic payoff g(T)X(T). Hence,
Vd(t)=βd(t)Etd[βd(T)g(T)X(T)], where Etd[⋅] represents the same operator under Qd. Importantly, to preclude arbitrage, we
find that Vf(t) and Vd(t) must also be linked by the spot rate. Specifically, we have
Vd(t)=X(t)Vf(t), or
βd(t)Etd[βd(T)g(T)X(T)]=X(t)βf(t)Etf[βf(T)g(T)]. If we now consider the arbitrary payoff Y(T):=βd(T)g(T)X(T), the above shows that
Etd[Y(T)]=Etd[Y(T)X(T)βf(T)βd(t)X(t)βf(t)βd(T)]. By our earlier theory, this shows that the density process linking Qd and Qf is given by
Etd[dQddQf]=βd(t)X(0)βf(t)X(t),t≥0. Because we know that this density process is a martingale under Qd, if X(t) is to be an Ito process, it
must take the form
X(t)dX(t)=(rd(t)−rf(t))dt+σX(t)⊺dW(t), under Qd, i.e. its drift is completely determined by the spread in the short-rates between the two
economies.
Other Measures
Heuristically, by using a relation analogous to the chain rule applied to Radon-Nikodym derivatives, relations
between other domestic and foreign probabilty measures are easy to deduce. Suppose our desired numeraire is N, with
values Nd and Nf in the domestic and foreign economies respectively. Denote the measures under these numeraires
by QN,d and QN,f under the domestic and foreign currencies respectively. Then, we find
that
EtN,d[dQN,ddQN,f]=βf(t)Nf(t)/Nf(0)⋅βd(t)X(0)βf(t)X(t)⋅Nd(t)/Nd(0)βd(t)=Nf(0)X(0)Nd(t)Nf(t)X(t)Nd(0). In particular, if we set N to be the T-bond in each currency, by noting the formula for the FX forward rate we see
that
EtT,d[dQT,ddQT,f]=XT(0)XT(t). This also demonstrates the fact that XT(t) is a QT,d-martingale satisfying XT(T)=X(T).