Multi-Currency Markets

Interest Rate Modeling




Tutorial Contents

  1. Fixed Income Notation
  2. Fixed Income Probability Measures
  3. Multi-Currency Markets
  4. The HJM Framework
  5. Basic Fixed Income Instruments
  6. Caps, Floors and Swaptions
  7. CMS Swaps, Caps and Floors
  8. Bermudan Swaptions
  9. Structured Notes and Exotic Swaps
  10. Callable Libor Exotics and TARNs
  11. Volatility Derivatives
  12. Yield Curves and Curve Construction
  13. Managing Yield Curve Risk
  14. Vanilla Models With Local Volatility
  15. Vanilla Models With Stochastic Volatility
  16. Introduction to Term Structure Models
  17. One-Factor Short Rate Models I
  18. One-Factor Short Rate Models II
  19. Multi-Factor Short Rate Models
  20. The Libor Market Model I
  21. The Libor Market Model II
  22. Risk Management and Sensitivity Computations
  23. P&L Attribution
  24. Payoff Smoothing
  25. Vegas in the Libor Market Model


Some derivatives depend on multiple currencies. If this is the case, the challenge of modeling such derivatives becomes more difficult. In this section, we introduce a framework for modeling such multi-currency derivatives.

Notation

Consider a setup where we have two economies, a domestic economy and a foreign economy, each with their own currency. In the following, we will denote the domestic currency by £ (GBP) and the foreign currency by $ (USD). Note that these choices of currencies are arbitrary and are just used for concreteness.

Let Pd(t,T)P_d(t,T) and Pf(t,T)P_f(t,T) denote the time tt prices of TT-bonds in the domestic and foreign economies, respectively. Translating the value of the foreign TT-bond to the domestic currency can be achieved at time tt through the spot FX rate X(t)X(t) measured in units of domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. In other words, the value P^d(t,T)\hat{P}_d(t,T) to a domestic investor of one foreign TT-bond is

P^d(t,T)=X(t)Pf(t,T). \hat{P}_d(t,T) = X(t)P_f(t,T).

FX Forwards

For no initial cash outlay, it is possible to generate a guaranteed cashflow at time TT of one unit of foreign c currency and XT(t)-X_T(t) units of domestic currency, where XT(t)X_T(t) represents the time tt value of the forward FX rate with maturity TT. The strategy is as follows:

  1. Buy one foreign TT-bond for P^d(t,T)\hat{P}_d(t,T) in domestic currency.
  2. Finance this purchase by short-selling P^d(t,T)Pd(t,T)\tfrac{\hat{P}_d(t,T)}{P_d(t,T)} units of the domestic TT-bond. Clearly, this strategy is free to enter, and will generate a time TT cashflow of $1£P^d(t,T)Pd(t,T)\$1 - £\tfrac{\hat{P}_d(t,T)}{P_d(t,T)}. To preclude arbitrage, we find that this expression must be zero at time tt. Hence, we have locked in an exchange rate of
    XT(t):=P^d(t,T)Pd(t,T)=X(t)Pf(t,T)Pd(t,T) X_T(t) := \frac{\hat{P}_d(t,T)}{P_d(t,T)} = X(t)\frac{P_f(t,T)}{P_d(t,T)}
    at time tt for an FX trade at maturity TT.

Risk Neutral Measures

Let βd(t)\beta_d(t) and βf(t)\beta_f(t) denote the continuously compounded money markets in the domestic and foreign economies, respectively. βd(t)\beta_d(t) and βf(t)\beta_f(t) induce two separate risk-neutral measures, which we denote by Qd\mathbb{Q}^d and Qf\mathbb{Q}^f, respectively. Clearly, these two measures are related. If g(T)g(T) is a random payoff at time TT made in the foreign currency, in a complete market this payoff is worth

Vf(t)=βf(t)Etf[g(T)βf(T)], V_f(t) = \beta_f(t) \mathbb{E}_t^f \left[\frac{g(T)}{\beta_f(T)} \right],

to the foreign investor, where Etf[]\mathbb{E}_t^f[\cdot] represents the conditional expectation operator under Qf\mathbb{Q}^f. From the point of view of a domestic investor, the payoff g(T)g(T) must translate to a domestic currency at a rate of X(T)X(T) at time TT, making the effective domestic payoff g(T)X(T)g(T)X(T). Hence,

Vd(t)=βd(t)Etd[g(T)X(T)βd(T)], V_d(t) = \beta_d(t)\mathbb{E}_t^d \left[\frac{g(T)X(T)}{\beta_d(T)} \right],

where Etd[]\mathbb{E}_t^d[\cdot] represents the same operator under Qd\mathbb{Q}^d. Importantly, to preclude arbitrage, we find that Vf(t)V_f(t) and Vd(t)V_d(t) must also be linked by the spot rate. Specifically, we have

Vd(t)=X(t)Vf(t), V_d(t) = X(t)V_f(t),

or

βd(t)Etd[g(T)X(T)βd(T)]=X(t)βf(t)Etf[g(T)βf(T)]. \beta_d(t)\mathbb{E}_t^d \left[\frac{g(T)X(T)}{\beta_d(T)} \right] = X(t) \beta_f(t) \mathbb{E}_t^f \left[\frac{g(T)}{\beta_f(T)} \right].

If we now consider the arbitrary payoff Y(T):=g(T)X(T)βd(T)Y(T) := \tfrac{g(T)X(T)}{\beta_d(T)}, the above shows that

Etd[Y(T)]=Etd[Y(T)X(t)βf(t)βd(T)X(T)βf(T)βd(t)]. \mathbb{E}_t^d\left[ Y(T)\right] = \mathbb{E}_t^d\left[ Y(T) \frac{X(t)\beta_f(t)\beta_d(T)}{X(T)\beta_f(T)\beta_d(t)}\right].

By our earlier theory, this shows that the density process linking Qd\mathbb{Q}^d and Qf\mathbb{Q}^f is given by

Etd[dQfdQd]=βf(t)X(t)βd(t)X(0),t0. \mathbb{E}_t^d \left[\frac{\text{d}\mathbb{Q}^f}{\text{d}\mathbb{Q}^d} \right] = \frac{\beta_f(t)X(t)}{\beta_d(t)X(0)}, \quad t \ge 0.

Because we know that this density process is a martingale under Qd\mathbb{Q}^d, if X(t)X(t) is to be an Ito process, it must take the form

dX(t)X(t)=(rd(t)rf(t))dt+σX(t)dW(t), \frac{\text{d}X(t)}{X(t)} = (r_d(t) - r_f(t))\text{d}t + \sigma_X(t)^\intercal \text{d}W(t),

under Qd\mathbb{Q}^d, i.e. its drift is completely determined by the spread in the short-rates between the two economies.

Other Measures

Heuristically, by using a relation analogous to the chain rule applied to Radon-Nikodym derivatives, relations between other domestic and foreign probabilty measures are easy to deduce. Suppose our desired numeraire is NN, with values NdN_d and NfN_f in the domestic and foreign economies respectively. Denote the measures under these numeraires by QN,d\mathbb{Q}^{N, d} and QN,f\mathbb{Q}^{N, f} under the domestic and foreign currencies respectively. Then, we find that

EtN,d[dQN,fdQN,d]=Nf(t)/Nf(0)βf(t)βf(t)X(t)βd(t)X(0)βd(t)Nd(t)/Nd(0)=Nf(t)X(t)Nd(0)Nf(0)X(0)Nd(t).\begin{aligned} & \mathbb{E}_t^{N,d}\left[\frac{\text{d}\mathbb{Q}^{N,f}}{\text{d}\mathbb{Q}^{N,d}} \right] \\ & = \frac{N_f(t)/N_f(0)}{\beta_f(t)}\cdot \frac{\beta_f(t)X(t)}{\beta_d(t)X(0)}\cdot\frac{\beta_d(t)}{N_d(t)/N_d(0)} \\ & = \frac{N_f(t)X(t)N_d(0)}{N_f(0)X(0)N_d(t)}. \end{aligned}

In particular, if we set NN to be the TT-bond in each currency, by noting the formula for the FX forward rate we see that

EtT,d[dQT,fdQT,d]=XT(t)XT(0). \mathbb{E}_t^{T,d}\left[\frac{\text{d}\mathbb{Q}^{T,f}}{\text{d}\mathbb{Q}^{T,d}} \right] = \frac{X_T(t)}{X_T(0)}.

This also demonstrates the fact that XT(t)X_T(t) is a QT,d\mathbb{Q}^{T,d}-martingale satisfying XT(T)=X(T)X_T(T) = X(T).

© 2022 Will Douglas, All Rights Reserved.