Crucial to the modeling of interest rate derivatives is the risk-neutral pricing framework. This framework is expressed in the language of stochastic processes and two particularly important concepts are that of an equivalent martingale measure and a numeraire. In this post, we will introduce the theory behind these concepts and then give some common and useful measures.
In this section, we review the key results from stochastic calculus and modern asset pricing theory. The results we uncover will give us a framework for pricing assets in a way that is consistent with the idea of no-arbitrage, a key assumption to mathematical finance. The following is technical and it is not crucial that you understand the theory inside out. The only crucial result is that of the equivalent martingale measure and corresponding numeraire. Keep that in mind if you find this section too advanced.
Consider an economy with continuous and frictionless trading, taking place on a finite time horizon . We assume the existence of traded, dividend-free assets, whose prices are characterized by the vector-valued stochastic process . Here, a stochastic process is simply a continuous set of vector-valued random variables, indexed by the time .
To model uncertainty and the flow of information, we introduce a probability space . Here, is a sample space with elements representing states of the world (or outcomes) that may materialise. represents a specific -algebra on (we will later see which one), effectively a family of subsets of outcomes from that satisfies certain conditions. represents a probability measure on the measure space . The details of the above setup require an understanding of the field of measure theory. Again, it is not important you understand this thoroughly. Just know that for each we find that and that , i.e. is a function that takes sets of outcomes and maps them to a number between 0 and 1 in such a way that each of these mappings can be considered a probability and can be considered a probability measure.
We model the flow of information through time via a filtration , a family of sub--algebras of satisfying whenever . The best way to think about is as the information available at time . As time passes, more and more information is revealed, so that incorporates all of the previous information up to time , plus any additional information gained from to .
We will assume that the process is adapted to for all . Practically speaking, this just means that is fully observable at time . Finally, we require that the filtration satisifes the usual conditions, which I will leave to the interested reader to explore further.
Let represent the expectation operator for the measure . When conditioning on information up to time , we will use the notation .
The above setup is fairly flexible. For our purposes, we focus on the situation where information is completely governed by a -dimensional vector-valued Brownian Motion , where is independent of for all . Again, it is not important to understand the technical details of Brownian motion on any particularly deep level. For now it suffices to say: , for and that each of these increments are independent of one another for non-overlapping times.
Above, we mentioned that represents a specific -algebra on . In fact, it is the one generated by , i.e., for all we have and .
We will assume that is described by the vector-valued Ito process
where and are both themselves adapted processes.
An incredibly powerful and useful concept that we require for our framework is that of a martingale. Before giving the precise definition, I will note that the concept of a martingale is really a simple one. A process is a martingale if the best guess for where the process will be in the future is where it is today. In this way, it represents a fair game, in the sense that if the martingale's current value represented the cost of entering into a bet, and it's future value your payoff from the bet, then you would on average expect to come out flat from playing the game.
Let be an adapted vector-valued process with for all . We say that is a martingale under the measure if, for all ,
The second important concept that we require is known as Ito's Lemma. Ito's lemma is essentially the stochastic version of the differential of a function. If we consider a simple scalar-valued function then the standard differential of is clearly just given by
This follows as the first order limit to the Taylor expansion
where H.O.T. represents the higher-order terms in the expansion, and .
This is all well and good while and are deterministic. If we were to assume that was our deterministic time variable, but was some stochastic variable of the form (2.1), then we have a different story. The notion of a differential breaks, since our higher order terms are no longer well-behaved. In particular, we have , where it can be shown that in quadratic mean. Thus, we see that in the first order limit, the stochastic case leads to differential
Ito's Lemma extends this result to scalar-valued functions of multiple variables.
Let , , denote a continuous function, let for all , , and let . Let be given by (2. 1) and define a scalar process . Let represent the -dimensional vector of partial derivatives of with respect to the non-time variables. Likewise, let represent the Hessian of with respect to the same variables. Then is an Ito process with stochastic differential given by
Consider an investor engaging in a trading strategy involving the assets . Let the trading strategy be characterized by a predictable adapted process , with denoting the holding at time in the th asset . The value of the trading strategy at time is thus given by
Clearly, over a small time interval , the gain from trading is given by , suggesting that
is an appropriate model for trading gains in an infinitesimal interval.
A trading strategy is said to be self-financing if, for any ,
This relationship expresses the concept that changes in portfolio value are solely caused by trading gains or losses, with no funds being added or withdrawn.
An arbitrage opportunity is a self-financing strategy for which and, for some ,
In words, an arbitrage opportunity is a strategy that creates something from nothing, a free lunch. In a well-functioning market, arbitrage opportunities cannot exist. If they did, they would surely be exploited until the market returned to equilibrium at a level that eliminated the opportunity. No arbitrage will form a key requirement for all of the markets that we will consider.
Currently, the idea of an arbitrage opportunity is an abstract one that bears no relation to the rest of our setup. However, one of the key insights of modern asset pricing is that under certain conditions, we can encapsulate no-arbitrage via the concept of an equivalent martingale measures.
First, note that two probability measures and on the same measure space are equivalent if for all . Shown via the Radon-Nikodymn Theorem, two equivalent measures are connected through a process with such that for all , known as the Radon-Nikodym derivative. is often denoted by . Now, an equivalent martingale measure for the process is simply an equivalent measure such that under , is a martingale.
With these concept in place, we now introduce the important concept of a numeraire.
A numeraire is a traded asset (a linear combination of our assets) with strictly positive price that pays no dividends, used to normalise the asset process. Denoting the numeraire value at time by , the normalized asset process is given by .
We say that a measure is an equivalent martingale measure induced by if is a martingale under . We call a trading strategy permissible if
is a martingale under .
The last concept that we introduce is that of a complete market. Roughly, a complete market is one where the assets are the only ones that matter, in the sense that all other assets can be generated as a linear combination of the s.
A complete market is one in which all finite-variance -measurable random variables can be replicated, in the sense that there exists a permisible trading strategy such that .
Via the fundamental theorems of asset pricing, we are now in a position to link all of these concepts, in a way that gives us a practical way of pricing derivatives.
Restricting attention to permissible trading strategies, the following two equivalencies hold:
Using the above, if we assume that our market is both arbitrage-free and complete then for each numeraire , there is a corresponding equivalent martingale measure . Hence, we can unambigously talk about the numeraire, measure pair . Under this pair, any -maturity derivative security paying out the random payoff at time can be expressed via
or
where .
Clearly, since is arbitrary in the above, if have another numeraire pair then
If we consider the time payoff then this shows that
By comparison, this shows that the Radon-Nikodym derivative for the measure change between measures and is characterised by the process
We have established that there is a close link between the concept of arbitrage and the existence and uniqueness of an equivalent martingale measure. We saw that there is even an easy way to characterize the Radon-Nikodym derivative linking two equivalent martingale measures via their corresponding numeraires. From a practical perspective, this does not tell us a huge amount about how we convert our asset price dynamics when acting under different numeraires. However, in the setup that we have introduced above, there is a practical way of switching between measures.
Consider two measures, and related by the density , where is an exponential martingale given by the Ito process
The -dimensional process is known as the market price of risk. Assuming that defines a martingale, we have the following important result:
Suppose that defined above is a martingale, then for all
is a Brownian motion under the measure .
As we have seen, selecting an equivalent martingale measure is largely a matter of choosing a numeraire. Here, we go through a number of important numeraires used in fixed income pricing. Throughout, we assume that our market precludes arbitrage and is complete, and we use to denote the time price of a derivative security making an -measurable payment of .
The most fundamental numeraire in the fixed-income world (and even more generally in derivatives pricing) is the continuously compounded money market account , satisfying the locally deterministic SDE
where is the same short rate that we saw in Section 1. Solving this SDE shows that
We denote the equivalent martingale measure associated with by . Under this measure, we find that
Utilising the explicit formula (2.3), we find that the above is equivalent to
As we saw in the Section 1, a ZCB pays out 1 unit at its maturity . Hence, if we set then for and we arrive at the bond pricing formula
This result is important because it shows that specification of the dynamics of the short-rate under is enough to determine ZCB prices at all times and maturities. Models based on such a direct specification are known as short rate models. Note the similarity between (2.5) and (1.1). Clearly, if is deterministic then the two expressions will agree and for all . However, if is random, these two results diverge, and we find that . However, if we were to replace by the equivalent futures rate then the above does hold. The exact result goes as follows.
Assuming that mark-to-market takes place continuously, under regularity conditions on , futures rate is a -martingale, and
Proving this result is relatively simple. We exploit the fact that the mark-to-market process leads to daily cash proceeds proportional to . Deflating each of these back to the current time and noting that the futures value is always zero shows that holding the futures contract until an arbitrary time leads to the expression . Since this holds for arbitrary time horizons, we deduce that
which implies that is a -martingale. The result follows immediately.
Taking the limit as on both sides of the above then gives our result for the instantaneous futures rate, i.e.
The -forward measure uses the -bond as numeraire. We will denote the conditional expectation operator under the -forward measure by , so that
By comparing (2.4) and (2.6), it should be clear that switching from the risk-neutral to the -forward measure decouples the expectation of the discount factor from the expectation of the payoff . This is often convenient when pricing IR derivatives. From equation (2.2), we see that the change of measure process from the risk-neutral to the -forward measure is given by density
Since the -bond is another traded asset and has price , we find that by definition, the time forward bond price is a martingale under the -forward measure. This is, in fact, where the name -forward measure comes from.
While the forward bond price is a martingale under the forward measure, we find that the forward Libor rate is a martingale under the -forward measure . This follows immediately from the relation
Using this fact, we find that
a result analogous to that of the futures rate result under the risk-neutral measure.
When working on a full tenor structure of forward rates, it can be inconvenient to work with a particular forward measure . Evolving through time, once , our numeraire is invalidated and we must switch measure to one that is still live. Another way to avoid this issue is by introducing a numeraire that extends to arbitrary horizons by construction. While the money market account accomplishes this, it can be awkward to work with an inherently continuous construct when dealing with a discrete tenor structure. An alternative is the discrete-time equivalent to .
At time , we invest £ in -bonds. Clearly, at , this investment returns
Reinvesting (rolling) this amount at into -bonds then returns
at . While , this investment clearly has value . By repeating this strategy at each date in the tenor structure, we arrive at an investment with time value given by
where we have again used the shorthand .
Since we constructed through a permissible trading strategy and for all , is a valid numeraire. The measure generated by is called the spot (Libor) measure, denoted by with associated conditional expectation . Then
where
It is clear that the spot measure resembles the risk neutral measure, since the risk-neutral measure is in some sense its continuous counterpart. In fact, if the futures rate is marked-to-market discretely, on dates , it turns out to be a martingale under the spot measure.
The big advantage of the spot measure that we discussed was that it remains alive throughout the span of the tenor structure. This property is key for valuing securities which may mature at any date in the tenor structure (e.g. barriers or range accruals).
Clearly, picking the -forward measure corresponding to the final maturity in the tenor structure, i.e. also satisfies this neat property. The measure induced by , is called the terminal measure. As usual,
One interpretation of the term is as the time proceeds of rolling the payoff into the -bond. Alternatively, we could roll into the spot numeraire asset , leading to payoff . This gives rise to the equivalent formula
Clearly, this idea generalises. For instance, we can define a numeraire such as
This asset corresponds to the strategy of initially investing into the -bond and then rolling our proceeds into the spot measure at . Letting denote the corresponding measure with conditional expectation operator , we can write
The associated measure to such numeraire is known as a hybrid measure. Clearly, many such hybrid measures exist and can be useful for different situations.
Since the annuity factor of Section 1 is just a linear combination of ZCBs, it qualifies as a numeraire asset. The associated measure is known as a swap measure or annuity measure. We have
where denotes the expectation operator under .
In the absence of arbitrage, the forward swap rate , which we have seen is defined by
is clearly a martingale under , giving the measure its name.